You have 3 free guides left 😟
Unlock your guides
You have 3 free guides left 😟
Unlock your guides

The is a key concept in economic growth theory. It explains how , labor growth, and technological progress drive long-term economic growth. This model provides insights into why some countries grow faster than others and predicts in living standards over time.

The model's assumptions and implications are crucial for understanding economic development. It highlights the importance of savings, investment, and technological advancement in fostering growth. While simplified, the Solow model serves as a foundation for more complex growth theories and policy discussions.

Solow Growth Model Assumptions

Production Function and Key Inputs

Top images from around the web for Production Function and Key Inputs
Top images from around the web for Production Function and Key Inputs
  • The Solow growth model is a neoclassical model of economic growth that emphasizes the role of capital accumulation, labor growth, and technological progress in determining long-run economic growth
  • The model assumes a closed economy with no government intervention, where output is determined by a Cobb-Douglas with constant returns to scale
  • The production function in the Solow model is given by Y=F(K,AL)Y = F(K, AL), where YY is output, KK is capital, LL is labor, and AA represents the level of technology
  • Example: The Cobb-Douglas production function could take the form Y=Kα(AL)1αY = K^{\alpha}(AL)^{1-\alpha}, where α\alpha is the output elasticity of capital

Savings, Investment, and Capital Accumulation

  • The model assumes that a constant fraction of output, denoted by ss, is saved and invested in new capital each period, while the remaining fraction (1s)(1-s) is consumed
  • Capital accumulation in the Solow model is determined by the difference between investment (savings) and depreciation, where depreciation is assumed to occur at a constant rate δ\delta
  • Example: If the is 20% and the is 5%, then the change in capital stock is equal to ΔK=0.20Y0.05K\Delta K = 0.20Y - 0.05K

Exogenous Labor and Technology Growth

  • The labor force grows at an exogenous rate nn, which is determined by factors outside the model, such as population growth
  • Technological progress in the Solow model is assumed to be labor-augmenting (Harrod-neutral) and occurs at an exogenous rate gg
  • Example: If the is 2% and the rate of technological progress is 1%, then the effective labor force (AL)(AL) grows at a rate of 3% per year

Steady-State Capital and Output

Steady-State Conditions

  • In the of the Solow model, capital per effective worker (k)(k^*) and output per effective worker (y)(y^*) are constant over time
  • The steady-state level of capital per effective worker (k)(k^*) is determined by setting the change in capital per effective worker equal to zero: Δk=sf(k)(n+g+δ)k=0\Delta k = sf(k) - (n + g + \delta)k = 0
    • This condition states that, in the steady state, investment per effective worker (sf(k))(sf(k)) must equal the amount of investment required to maintain the existing level of capital per effective worker ((n+g+δ)k)((n + g + \delta)k)

Solving for Steady-State Levels

  • The steady-state level of output per effective worker (y)(y^*) can be found by substituting the steady-state level of capital per effective worker (k)(k^*) into the production function: y=f(k)y^* = f(k^*)
  • To find the steady-state levels of capital and , multiply kk^* and yy^* by the level of technology AA: K/L=AkK/L = Ak^* and Y/L=AyY/L = Ay^*
  • Example: If the production function is Y=K0.3(AL)0.7Y = K^{0.3}(AL)^{0.7}, the savings rate is 0.2, the population growth rate is 0.02, the rate of technological progress is 0.01, and the depreciation rate is 0.05, then the steady-state level of capital per effective worker is k5.19k^* \approx 5.19 and the steady-state level of output per effective worker is y1.48y^* \approx 1.48

Convergence to Steady State

  • The Solow model predicts that, in the long run, the economy will converge to the steady state, regardless of its initial level of capital
  • The speed of convergence depends on the distance between the current level of capital per effective worker and the steady-state level
  • Example: If an economy starts with a low level of capital per worker relative to its steady state, it will experience rapid growth as it accumulates capital and converges to the steady state

Growth Effects on Steady-State Output

Changes in the Saving Rate

  • An increase in the saving rate (s)(s) leads to a higher steady-state level of capital per effective worker (k)(k^*) and, consequently, a higher steady-state level of output per effective worker (y)(y^*)
    • A higher saving rate means that more output is invested in capital accumulation, leading to a higher capital stock in the steady state
  • Example: If the saving rate increases from 20% to 25%, the steady-state levels of capital and output per effective worker will increase, leading to higher long-run growth

Changes in Population Growth

  • An increase in the population growth rate (n)(n) reduces the steady-state level of capital and output per effective worker
    • A higher population growth rate means that more investment is required to maintain the existing level of capital per worker, as the capital stock must be spread over a larger number of workers
  • Example: If the population growth rate increases from 2% to 3%, the steady-state levels of capital and output per effective worker will decrease, leading to lower long-run growth

Changes in Technological Progress

  • An increase in the rate of technological progress (g)(g) leads to a higher steady-state level of output per effective worker (y)(y^*) but does not affect the steady-state level of capital per effective worker (k)(k^*)
    • Faster technological progress increases the effectiveness of labor, allowing for higher output per worker in the steady state
  • Example: If the rate of technological progress increases from 1% to 2%, the steady-state level of output per effective worker will increase, leading to higher long-run growth

Transitional Dynamics

  • Changes in the saving rate, population growth rate, or rate of technological progress will cause the economy to transition to a new steady state over time, with the speed of convergence depending on the model's parameters
  • During the transition, the growth rate of output per worker will be higher or lower than the steady-state growth rate, depending on whether the economy is converging to a higher or lower steady state
  • Example: If the saving rate increases, the economy will experience a period of rapid growth as it converges to the new, higher steady state, with the growth rate gradually slowing down as it approaches the steady state

Convergence Across Countries

Conditional Convergence

  • The Solow model predicts conditional convergence, meaning that countries with similar saving rates, population growth rates, and technology will converge to the same steady-state level of output per worker in the long run, regardless of their initial conditions
  • Countries with lower initial levels of capital per worker will grow faster than those with higher initial levels, as they are further from their steady state and have a higher marginal product of capital
  • Example: If two countries have the same saving rate, population growth rate, and technology, but one starts with a lower level of capital per worker, the poorer country will grow faster and eventually catch up to the richer country

Factors Affecting Convergence

  • The model suggests that differences in saving rates, population growth rates, and technological progress can explain persistent differences in income levels across countries
  • Policies that increase the saving rate, reduce population growth, or promote technological progress can help poorer countries converge to the income levels of richer countries
  • Example: If a developing country implements policies to increase its saving rate and promote technological adoption, it can accelerate its convergence to the income levels of developed countries

Limitations and Extensions of the Solow Model

  • The Solow model has been criticized for its simplifying assumptions and its inability to fully explain cross-country income differences, leading to the development of endogenous growth theories and other extensions of the model
  • These extensions incorporate factors such as human capital, research and development, and institutions to provide a more comprehensive explanation of long-run growth and convergence
  • Example: The Mankiw-Romer-Weil model extends the Solow model by including human capital as an additional factor of production, helping to explain a larger portion of cross-country income differences

Empirical Evidence on Convergence

  • Empirical evidence on convergence is mixed, with some studies finding support for conditional convergence and others highlighting the importance of factors not included in the basic Solow model, such as human capital, institutions, and geography
  • Studies have found that countries with similar characteristics tend to converge to similar income levels, but the speed of convergence is often slower than predicted by the Solow model
  • Example: The "East Asian Miracle" countries (Hong Kong, Singapore, South Korea, and Taiwan) experienced rapid growth and convergence to developed country income levels, driven by high saving rates, investments in human capital, and export-oriented policies
© 2024 Fiveable Inc. All rights reserved.
AP® and SAT® are trademarks registered by the College Board, which is not affiliated with, and does not endorse this website.


© 2024 Fiveable Inc. All rights reserved.
AP® and SAT® are trademarks registered by the College Board, which is not affiliated with, and does not endorse this website.

© 2024 Fiveable Inc. All rights reserved.
AP® and SAT® are trademarks registered by the College Board, which is not affiliated with, and does not endorse this website.
Glossary
Glossary